This page is optimized for mobile devices, if you would prefer the desktop version just click here

0.17 Culture, value, and communication  (Page 3/3)

On the other hand, although public goods can be extended to more users at or near zero cost, they can be quitecostly to produce in the first place. The case of digitally produced scholarship is an excellent example. Economic theory tellsus is that we ought to charge nothing for it at the margin: we ought to give it away. On the other hand, it tells us nothing abouthow to pay for its production or how much of it to produce. It does tell us that markets will underproduce this kind of good, though,and it also tells us that, as a general matter, the solution of public-goods problems requires collective action.

Collectively, then, we should act to support the system of scholarly communication as a public good—and thiscollective action must be as broad as possible, including not only those universities with presses, but also all universities withfaculty, libraries, students, and public outreach. After all, the social value produced by the system as a whole is enjoyed by all ofthese constituents.

In considering how best to organize the publishing side of scholarly communication, it will also beimportant to be open to new business models. Received opinion and settled assumptions may be very costly, both in terms of missedopportunities and in terms of unforeseen expenses. For example, defying conventional wisdom, the National Academy Press has forsome time now been distributing the content of its monographs free on the Web, and (thanks in part to a carefully thought-out strategyfor doing that) it has seen its sales of print increase dramatically.

By comparison with print, born-digital scholarship will be expensive for publishers to create and, overtime, even more expensive for libraries to maintain. Even considering these costs, however, owning and maintaining digitalcollections locally or consortially, rather than renting access to them from commercial publishers, is likely to be a cost-cuttingstrategy in the long run. If universities do not own the content they produce—if they do not collect it, hold it, and preserveit—then commercial interests will certainly step in to do the job, and they will do it on the basis of market demand rather than as apublic good. If universities do collect, preserve, and provide open access to the content they produce, and if everyone in the systemof scholarly communication understands that the goods being produced and shared are in fact public goods and not privateproperty, the remaining challenge will be to determine how much, and what, to produce.

Such questions would normally be answered with reference to demand, and, indeed, one analysis of the “crisis inscholarly publishing” is that it is a crisis of audience. Average university-press print runs are now in the low hundreds, andalthough digital printing lowers the unit cost for printing short runs of books, selling fewer books raises the cost per copy to thelibrary or scholar and makes it harder for the publisher to cover pre-press costs, which are still the most significant portion ofthe total cost of producing a book or article. On the other hand, university presses could (and should) expand the audience forhumanities scholarship by making it more readily available online. Unless this public good can easily be found by the public—byreaders outside the university—demand is certain to be underestimated and undersupplied.

We note that some university presses have already made great strides in electronic publishing—Johns Hopkins’sProject MUSE,

Illinois’s History Cooperative, and the University of Virginia Press’s Rotunda series, to name a few. The Rice University Press, closed in 1996, is being brought“back to life as the first fully digital university press in the United States.”
Rice University Press (External Link) .
Some scholarly societies, such as the American Historical Association, also have experimentedwith publishing born-digital scholarship. These and other experiments in electronic publishing in the humanities and socialsciences, and experiments in building and maintaining digital collections in libraries and institutional repositories, need to besupported as they move toward sustainability, and they need to be funded (by universities, by private foundations, and by the public)with the expectation that they will move toward open access—an area in which many of the natural sciences and some social sciences areconspicuously ahead of the humanities.
See John Willinsky, The Access Principle (Cambridge: Massachusetts Institute of Technology Press,2005).
Open-source software is an instructive analogue here, and the experience in that community suggests, strongly, that onecan build scalable and successful economic enterprises on the basis of free intellectual property.
See Bruce Perens, “The Emerging Economic Paradigm of Open Source” (External Link) (2005).
It is worth noting, too, that the “Economy of Regard” (that is, prestige)is one of the factors used to explain why this open economy works.
See Paul A. David and Rishab Aiyer Ghosh, “Free and Open Source Software Developers and ‘the Economy ofRegard’: A Quantitative Analysis of Code-Signing Patterns within the Linux Kernel,” Stanford Institute for Economic Policy Research,SIEPR-Project NOSTRA Working Paper, 2004 (External Link) .

As in the open-source community,

See Jill Coffin, “An Analysis of Open Source Principles in Diverse Collaborative Communities,” FirstMonday 11.6 (June 2006) (External Link) .
however, there are real resources in play, and those who contribute to themmust have some motivation to do so. According to Kate Wittenberg, director of Electronic Publishing in Columbia (EPIC), suchenterprises must “find a way in which the technical infrastructure and some aspects of workflow systems might be created centrally andthen shared by a variety of projects in the humanities and socialsciences.” She adds, “For EPIC and similar organizations, finding an answer to this challenge would be extremely valuable: [it wouldmake] use of existing infrastructure to create efficiencies inorganizations with minimal staffing.” One model of shared infrastructure outside the United States is Érudit,an initiative of Les Presses de l’Université de Montréal. Érudit offers a range of services tailored to different kinds of academicpublications and “is intended to serve as an innovative means of promoting and disseminating the results of university research.”
Érudit (External Link) .
Another model might be a scaled-up version of EPIC itself, which is acollaboration among Columbia University’s press, libraries, and academic information systems. The cooperation between the University of California Press and the California DigitalLibrary is another promising example.

<< Chapter < Page Page > Chapter >>

Read also:

OpenStax, "our cultural commonwealth" the report of the american council of learned societies commission on cyberinfrastructure for the humanities and social sciences. OpenStax CNX. Dec 15, 2006 Download for free at http://cnx.org/content/col10391/1.2
Google Play and the Google Play logo are trademarks of Google Inc.
Jobilize.com uses cookies to ensure that you get the best experience. By continuing to use Jobilize.com web-site, you agree to the Terms of Use and Privacy Policy.